Electoral Politics and Voting in Australia

With the July 2nd Federal election looming large in Australia, the airwaves, and the internet and print media have become engulfed with the usual onslaught of political advertisements, commentary, sound bites, ‘gotcha’ moments, and everything else that characterises modern election campaigns. In amongst these messages, there have been a number of calls to action (particularly from the mainstream political ‘left’), telling us how important it is to get out to vote and to enact our democratic rights, which are both a privilege and a responsibility. Prominent among these has been Waleed Aly’s passionate plea to the 500,000 Australians between the ages of 18 and 24 who are not enrolled to vote, asking them “what are you thinking?” when it is within their grasp to “completely change the outcome of this election” if they just went out and enrolled. Implicit in these messages is the assertion that we can change Australia for the better, if only we work within the political system, and take the election and its options seriously, which young Australians do not appear to be doing. A few questions arise, however: Is it really that important to take elections seriously and to vote? Do average voters really have the power that they are being made out to have? And, are elections in Australia and other western democracies really vehicles for progressive social change as is assumed? In answering these questions, I will argue that a belief in the importance of elections could in fact hamper positive long-term change. At the same time, however, I will argue that your vote can make a difference, and will outline (for what it’s worth) what I plan to do on election day.

In order to answer the questions posed above, it is necessary to explore how the political system in western parliamentary democracies, such as that found in Australia, actually functions. In the idealized model, elections represent those occasions when the population comes together to choose, from amongst their number, those representatives who best capture their own views, and who will most forcefully fight for their interests. The population is assumed to be fully informed on all issues, and their voting decisions are outcomes of compromises between all possible positions on all possible issues that confront the nation at that time and into the future. The Median Voter Model (MVM) – which probably best captures this idealized view in the Political Science literature – suggests that political parties form around blocks of voters with similar views, and that political parties will emerge to represent all the blocks across the entire political spectrum of views within the society. Over the longer term, the political parties are thought to converge around the ‘median voter’; that is, the hypothetical person who best captures the centre of the political spectrum, and who represents the point of most equal and fair compromise between the views of the population as a whole. From the MVM perspective, parliaments are truly democratic, and embody what a population believes on all important issues at the time of an election.

Mainstream discourse on elections implicitly (or explicitly) assumes the MVM to be a true and accurate portrayal of the functioning of parliamentary democracies, such as Australia’s. Politicians regularly appeal to the “average Australian” when announcing policy platforms; political commentators grumble that this or that legislative change will not be to the liking of “middle Australia”, and governments commonly claim to have achieved a democratic mandate for change after winning an election. The evidence for the MVM is not strong, however. First, its assumption that the population is fully informed on all issues is not only implausible, but demonstrably false. Second, confidence in political parties in Australia is quite low, with as few as 31% of Australians believing that political parties represent them (e.g., Martin, 2011). Third, members of the Australian parliament are not drawn proportionally from the different classes that make up the Australian population, with politicians being more likely to have attended private school, more likely to have attended university, more likely to own property, less likely to have been beneficiaries of (low SES) welfare provisions, and generally more likely to be wealthy than the average Australian. Finally, and most importantly, it is well known that the political establishment and the population – and by extension the ‘median voter’ – differ markedly on a whole range of issues, including health and education funding (the population typically wants more); support for overseas military intervention (the population typically wants less); support for climate change mitigation (the population typically wants more); and support for same-sex marriage (the population is strongly in favour), amongst many others. These points all undermine the MVM as an accurate and parsimonious account of elections and the political system in Australia.

An alternate model to the MVM is the Investment Theory of Party Competition (ITPC). The ITPC suggests that public policy arises not from competition for the median voter as the MVM suggests, but rather emerges from competition between business interests. Investors are thought to coalesce around political parties, and invest in them, as vehicles to protect and drive their interests. Those issues on which the groups of investors agree will be uncontested and invisible to the population, irrespective of the population’s interest in those issues. On those issues on which groups of investors disagree there will be fierce competition, again irrespective of the population’s interest or otherwise in those issues.

Within the ITPC, the interests of investors are thought to frame and constrain public policy throughout the life of any government that gains a majority. The population, however, only plays any significant role during election campaigns. Voters do not frame or constrain public policy, but they must be appealed to during elections, and therefore political parties must court them for their votes, which they typically do with issues that do not affect the core business interests of the investors that they represent. Capital-intensive industries – that is, those with lower labour costs and more capital investment – are able to court voters with higher wages, better working conditions, more progressive social policy, and can align themselves with unions, because these do not affect their core business interests. Labour-intensive industries – that is, those with higher labour costs and less capital investment – on the other hand, are unable to court voters with these same policies, because anything that increases the cost of labour will have strong negative effects on the profitability of these industries. As such, labour-intensive industries, and the political parties that represent them, commonly compete with rival parties on “values”, and induce fear, patriotism, and other such devices to court voters. In Australia, though the boundaries can be quite fluid, capital-intensive industries have typically supported the Labor Party, and labour-intensive industries have typically supported the Liberal Party (see, for example, AEC records on political donations).

The evidence for the ITPC, unlike the MVM, is quite strong (though admittedly no study that I am aware of has been conducted in the Australian context). First, the ITPC makes no prior assumptions about the degree to which voters are informed or otherwise, as the consequences of information flow in a money-run political system are peripheral, because the population is made to be largely peripheral. Second, the ITPC is entirely consistent with the class differences that exist between members of parliament and the general population. Third, the ITPC provides a plausible explanation for the emergence of the two-party systems common in western democracies, suggesting that they are an outcome of a deep schism in the interests of capital-intensive and labour-intensive industries. Third, various studies in the United States and in Europe have shown that public policy aligns strongly with the opinions of those at the top of the income ladder, and becomes increasingly divergent as you descend to the lowest rungs. And finally, and perhaps most importantly, careful research into the outcome of presidential elections in the United States, from the 1933 ‘New Deal’ election of Franklin D. Roosevelt to the election of Bill Clinton in 1992, provides direct support for the ITPC. This research tracks the views of investors, their relationships with party figures, and the money that flowed to the Democratic and Republican Parties in each election, and shows that public policy, and the results of the elections, largely arise from an interplay of these factors. The ITPC appears to explain existing political systems well, particularly those, such as Australia’s, where wealth and power are concentrated in the hands of a privileged few.

So where does this leave us with regard to the importance of voting in elections in Australia? Assuming that the ITPC provides an accurate portrayal of the functioning of the political system in Australia, a few points logically follow. First, the political parties on offer, particularly the two major parties, are unlikely to represent anywhere near the views of the electorate. From this it follows that the decision for many Australians on election day will be how to choose the least bad option from those they are being offered. This could go some way to explaining the disengagement of young Australians (and should, perhaps, be taken into account by anyone who ever feels like blaming other groups – particularly disaffected groups of less privileged people who have been made to focus on their own, often ethnocentric, interests – for the government we end up with after an election[1]).

It also follows from the ITPC that the way in which the population in Australia votes likely has very little impact on public policy, and is unlikely to lead to large-scale positive social change. Taking a historical perspective, it is quite clear that parliaments are in fact very conservative institutions, and rarely, if ever, lead the way in effecting change – a fact predicted by the ITPC. The history of slavery, workers’ rights, women’s rights, LGBTIQ rights, environmental action, and so on, shows that progressive social change arises from movements in the population, and that legislative changes follow much later, if at all.

Following from this point, the ITPC predicts that social change of the most progressive and revolutionary kind cannot occur until the power of investors to control the political process is curtailed. This could take various forms, the most obvious of which is the formation of trade unions embedded in the working population, something which has been attempted with some success in the past. In the long-term, however, only dismantling institutions in which power is concentrated, and democratizing them, is likely to lead to public policy that represents the views of the population. Minor parties can and do arise to challenge the political establishment (the Greens are the most obvious contemporary example in Australia), but their success can only be limited in the long-term. In the first instance, these parties will be ignored and will not have the resources to promote themselves or their policies. If they are able to survive this initial period, they will then become threatening to the political establishment, and will become targets for attack. If they are able to survive these attacks and establish themselves as a legitimate political force, they will become attractive to investors, who will begin to court them, invest in them, such that their policy positions will gradually start to reflect the views of those investors (a process that I think is beginning to play out at this moment with the Greens, and that can be seen in the history of the Labor party). If by some miracle, a party such as this survives with its values intact and wins government, then other means are available to concentrated power to undermine legislative changes. Large amounts of money can be invested in further attack campaigns (as occurred for the Carbon tax), prices on monopolized goods and services can be increased[2] (as occurred in Venezuela when the Chavez government enacted mildly progressive social policies), or investment capital can be moved across state borders, thus destroying the national economy (as occurred in Bolivia in the face of land reforms). Only the democratization of concentrated private power, and the spreading of wealth outside the hands of a few can truly lead to a political system that represents the views of its population.

In light of these points, it is perhaps not as clear as is often assumed, by Waleed Aly and others, that enrolling to vote, and voting in the upcoming election is as important as it is made out to be. By focussing all our attention on the election, and who we should vote for, when these actions will likely have little long-term effect, and will, for most, be a choice between a bad option and a worse option, we may in fact be distracting ourselves from what history has taught us: positive change comes about through mass popular movement, through the creation of solidarity among diverse groups with diverse interests, and through the dismantling of institutions of concentrated power. Positive social change comes about through working together, outside of the electoral cycle and outside of the political system, not through elections or through voting for candidates whose policy positions we have little impact on. Elections – though a privilege, given the long and violent struggles by past generations for the franchise – are not that important if the goal is to bring about progressive social change.

Having said all this, I want to finish by emphasizing that I do not believe that voting in the upcoming election is completely unimportant. The differences between the parties on some issues are very real, and will have very real consequences for people’s lives. The Greens’ positions on asylum seekers, climate change action, violence against women, and penalty rates, for example, are far more humane, and will be of far greater benefit to a greater number of people, than anything on offer by the Liberal or Labor Parties. These differences matter.  These differences particularly matter if you live in a marginal seat, where your vote can determine the outcome of the election. These differences also particularly matter in the senate, where your vote can determine how much the more destructive policies of whichever major party forms government can be curtailed. For what it’s worth, I will be voting informally (i.e., “donkey voting”) in the House of Representatives, and preferencing the Greens in the Senate. The safe Liberal seat in which I live means I can get away with a protest vote, and allows me to live up to what I really believe in. In the Senate, however, where my vote really matters, I do not want to see the more destructive elements of the political establishment gaining unbridled power, and I want to see progressive amendments made to any legislation that comes before that House. Whatever you decide to do on the 2nd of July, remember that your ability to bring about positive change extends well beyond your vote on that one day every 3-4 years.

 

[1] It is always a good idea to remember that, when systematically surveyed, Australians mostly hold quite socially progressive, and socially democratic views in most policy domains. It is also worth remembering that vulnerable, disaffected, less educated people are not the cause of the sickening policies (e.g., toward asylum seekers, women, indigenous Australians etc.) enacted by the government, and that with a bit of positive engagement (rather than the all-too-common comments about these people’s stupidity), we could all in fact be allies in the fight against the real oppressors who hold social, economic, and political power.

[2] When economists and business leaders predict increasing costs after some policy change that they are not fond of (for example, increases in electricity bills after the introduction of the carbon tax), I often think that these should be taken not as predictions, but rather as threats.

Liebster Award

The Goat Track to Freedom has been nominated for a Liebster Award by Vincent from Life is Frightening. Thanks, Vinny! The Liebster Award is a peer-nomination scheme that gives bloggers the opportunity to recommend other blogs they like.

Should they accept the nomination, bloggers are required (not a popular word on The Goat Track to Freedom, with its connotations of authority and domination) to share 11 random facts about themselves, answer 11 questions posed by their nominator, and then ask 11 questions of the bloggers they nominate. Given that I've only posted one article so far, I'm taking this as a proxy "About Me" section, and also as an opportunity to live up to some of the goals of The Goat Track to Freedom; creating connections between people and linking to other valuable resources that provide a similar perspective. It's also an opportunity to write something a bit more lighthearted than what would usually appear on this site.

11 Random Facts

1. I often ponder the deeper meaning of signs. For example, signs that say “Please put litter in the bin” create a paradox, because as soon as it’s in the bin, it ceases to be litter. I’ve considered emailing Stephen Hawking about this.

2. When I see road signs that say “Slow Point, 20kms/hr”, I point at them really slowly. If you actually try and point at 20kms/hr, it’s actually quite fast for pointing, so I usually aim for between 3 and 5 kms/hr.

stock-photo-6733448-slow-point-traffic-sign.jpg

3. I took a picture of a digital clock at 11:11am on the 11th of November, 2011. It reminds me of Asch’s famous line length study.

Clock.JPG

4. Everyone in my phone contact list is designated by a ridiculous nickname. Almost none of them know this.

5. I was born in Hong Kong, but despite appearances, I’m not actually Chinese.

6. I’m kinda scared of objects with irregular patterns of closely-spaced holes... I mean, how gross is this?

Holes.JPG

7. The capital of France is Paris.

8. I speak French, which means I know that many French terms adopted into English sound far less romantic when translated. For example, “pot pourri” literally means “rotten pot”, “crème brûlée” is French for “burnt cream”, and “cul-de-sac” means “arse of bag”. 

9. When I go to conferences, it often strikes me that there’s a disproportionate number of cul-de-sacs in academia, particularly at the level of Professor.

10. One of my favourite things in life is immersing myself in a crowd (e.g., at a protest or sporting event), and feeling the collective buzz of being surrounded by your fellow men and women. When Australia beat Uruguay on penalties in 2005 to qualify for the World Cup, I felt that collective buzz so strongly that I hugged about 15-20 random sweaty men. I hope each of them cherishes each of those moments of love as much as I do, even if it’s only the pungent aroma of their pheromones that keeps the memories alive.

11. Related to random fact 10, I discovered just the other day (at the Australia vs. Oman match in Sydney) why you should always book tickets to sporting events at the same time as your friends. If you don’t, not only will you not be sitting with your friends, but the Ticketek staff – no doubt laughing from their corporate boxes above (boo hierarchy!) – will turn you into a social pariah by allocating you a seat literally all alone (see diagram below). Imagine the sea of humanity around you, that collective buzz of the crowd, so near, yet so far... Imagine the loneliness as the Mexican wave passes around you but not through you... Imagine the stigma as everyone cheers and you sit awkwardly clapping, silently crying, desperately wanting to connect as the first goal goes in, but always only having that cold, hard plastic you’re sitting on to comfort you. Always book tickets at the same time as your friends.


11 Questions and my Answers 

1. What’s one thing that makes your life less shit?
Those signs in dog parks that say “pick up after your dog”... I think they make everyone’s life/shoes less shit.

2. If you could choose one person in the world to make a guest post on your blog, who would it be, and why?
Definitely Noam Chomsky, because then everyone could see how much he steals his ideas from me. Also, I think he might have a few other marginally interesting insights into world affairs.

3. If you weren’t blogging about what you blog about now, what would you be blogging about instead?
Probably the deeper meaning of signs. I have long wanted to do a feature article on the diversity of wet floor sign designs.

4. I’m good thanks – how are you?
Pretty good, but I could go a goat curry, with a side of freedom.

5. What do you most like about keeping a blog?
The incredible fame.

6. What’s the most annoying thing about blogging?
The paparazzi camped in my front courtyard.

7. What’s the most annoying thing about you?
How photogenic I am in gossip magazines... at least that’s what Kristen Stewart said when I asked her that question in bed last night.

8. Which band would you choose to write the soundtrack to your blog?
One Direction, because all goat tracks lead in one direction: towards freedom.

9. What is the capital of Madagascar? (this one is going to be very easy for the BBC blog)
Antananananananarivo... I never remember how many “na’s” there are and where to stop... like banananananananana.

10. If your blog were to make a significant change to the world, what would that change be?
Ideally, I would like my blog to lead to the complete collapse of the current system, to be replaced by a utopia characterised by complete liberty, peace, love, compassion, and the flourishing of art, science and culture. Failing that, I’d be happy if there were a 0.0001% increase in people saying “hey look, there’s a goat track!”

11. Life is frightening – what frightens you most?
I find this stylised depiction of what happens to your baby if you install his/her baby seat over the airbag quite frightening... The materialisation of that giant boomerang between the red (presumably blood-soaked?) baby and the airbag seems particularly concerning.

And to end on a more serious note, I find the degree to which our society endorses and promotes hierarchy and domination quite frightening.

 

My nominations

-The Only Adrienne - for being my Honours student... but also for being pretty funny (the pressure's on).
-Rethinking the Job Culture - for helping us rethink the job culture, and ask the question "why work?"

My questions for them

1.    Will you join the coming revolution?

2.    How do you feel about objects with irregular patterns of closely-spaced holes?

3.    Who is your favourite philosopher and why?

4.    Why do you blog?

5.    What do you hate most about blogging?

6.    How much is that doggy in the window?

7.    What random but interesting fact about the world have you learnt since the beginning of 2015?

8.    Who or what inspired you to start a blog?

9.    What’s the best pun you’ve ever come up with?

10.    What issue do you think most urgently needs to be addressed in the world today?

11.    Do you think freedom will necessarily lead to chaos? Why or why not?

 

And that's all folks! Don't worry, the next article (on Education, coming very soon) will be far more serious.

Freedom and Chaos

Centralized authority is a defining feature of Western liberal democracies, such as Australia. These societies are by no means totalitarian, but power within their institutions remains concentrated in the hands of a privileged few. In Australia, the government is run by the Prime Minister and his or her cabinet, corporations are under the direction of a CEO and a board of directors, universities are run by a Vice-Chancellor and an executive council, schools are run by a principal and a committee of executive teachers, and so forth. In each case, decision-making resides in an authority, which has the power to control the fate of the institution and the fate of those whose outcomes are bound up in the institution (e.g., citizens, workers, consumers, students etc.).

The legitimacy of these structures of authority is rarely questioned by those in power, for the obvious reason that existing institutions would cease to be “existing institutions” if they undermined themselves. These institutions also actively sustain themselves by propagating the belief that authority is not simply legitimate, but that it is in fact necessary for the proper functioning of the society. From an early age, children are taught that it is important to listen to and follow the instructions of their elders and parents, to defer to the powers that be, and to respect institutionalized authorities such as teachers, police officers, judges, and the offices of the Prime Minister, and the Governor-General. From these messages, children learn that others know better, and that there exists a class of intelligent and benevolent rulers who can protect them from “the rage and trampling of the bewildered herd”, as prominent public intellectual Walter Lippmann described the general population. Through the media, the population is further taught that authorities exist to protect them from external threats (such as “boat people” and other dangerous enemies), and to guide progress towards a better future (in the words of former US President Harry Truman, “where there is no leadership, society stands still”). If authority were to dissipate for whatever reason, people have been led to believe that society would naturally “descend into anarchy” until authorities “restore order” by “cracking down hard” and re-asserting themselves (ABC news, describing the aftermath of Hurricane Katrina in New Orleans in 2005). Within this dominant and pervasive framework, authority is equated with order, and freedom from authority is equated with chaos[1].

A question that naturally arises from this framework – which is rarely argued, but more commonly asserted or assumed – is whether freedom from authority necessarily entails a descent into disorder and chaos. Anecdotally, there appears to be no reason to equate the two concepts, despite the widespread acceptance of their association. Almost all the day-to-day interactions between people occur without domination by one party over the other and without formal structures of authority to manage those interactions, yet these interactions almost never end in stagnation or irresolvable impasse. The end of feudalism, slavery, absolutism, apartheid, and the continuing struggles to end domination of women by men, and of workers by their bosses are all characterized by challenges to structures of authority, and all have resulted in a better world, rather than a worse one. And the goat track – that potent symbol of bottom-up co-ordination that is the central metaphor of this blog – also implies that authority is not a necessary precursor to stability and structure.

At a more theoretical level, the same conclusions follow. A state of freedom – characterized by respect for the dignity of the individual, individual agency free of coercion, and distributed power – need not be equated with disorder, because there exist natural constraints – emanating from our shared experience of living in the same world and our shared characteristics as human beings – that limit the range of possible outcomes, guiding us away from absolute, unstructured chaos. At a very basic level, all human beings share the same universe – with the same physical laws – and the same planet – with the same manifestations of those laws. More meaningfully, all human beings share the same basic biology. We all (with a few exceptions) have two arms and two legs, a head, a heart, and the same set of internal organs. We all (again with a few exceptions) have a desire for survival, a need for food, a need for oxygen, and a genetic heritage that determines to a large extent how we will develop across our lifespans.

More meaningfully still, all human beings share the same basic cognitive structures and the same basic psychology. We all (again with marginal exceptions) have a social reasoning system, which allows us to interpret and react to the norms and customs that shape our community.  We also all have a ‘theory of mind’ system, which allows us to respond appropriately to, and with consideration for, the thoughts and feelings of those around us. We also all have a related moral reasoning system, which allows us to consider right and wrong and to make decisions with regard to the complex interplay of the conflicting interests of members of our community. Together, these physical, biological and psychological constraints definitively restrict the range of choices that we would conceivably make about how to organize our societies should existing structures of domination be dismantled, thus reducing the probability of utter chaos.

Of these constraints, the psychological constraints are the most important. The social reasoning, ‘theory of mind’, and moral reasoning systems each allow for coordinated action among individuals, which is the basis for orderly outcomes in the absence of authority. The social reasoning system provides us with the ability to learn, interpret, react to, and shape the norms and customs of the communities in which we live. When we come to identify with those around us – that is, to see ourselves as sharing commonalities and as being emotionally connected to our peers – we feel a strong need to reach consensus, and to decrease differences between ourselves and others. We become motivated to develop shared norms and customs, and to follow those shared norms and customs for their own sake. We develop symbols that define us as a collective, and we seek reassurance and validation from others. These near-universal human features suggest that coordinated action could win out over independent, competitive, or conflictual action, thus conceivably promoting stability and harmony over “anarchy” and mayhem when structures of authority are absent.

The ‘theory of mind’ system allows individuals to understand one another’s thoughts and feelings, and, importantly, to feel empathy for one another. By feeling one another’s feelings, human beings can truly experience the world from the point of view of another, and thereby make decisions in light of the interests of others.  In a practical sense, empathy is fundamental to cooperation, and to the desire to negotiate and to compromise in the face of conflict. The ‘theory of mind’ system constrains those choices that people are likely to make, and allows collectively beneficial outcomes to be achieved, again, in the absence of coercive authority.

Moral reasoning in human beings is less well understood, but like ‘theory of mind’ processes, it appears to be a human universal fundamental to coordinated action, and, as such, to be a buffer against chaos. Moral codes vary across communities and cultures, but at a basic level these moral codes share important features, and are mutually intelligible across communities and cultures. As argued by David Hume in the 18th century, and more recently by John Rawls in his Theory of Justice, it appears that human beings have an innate moral sense. When we behave in ways that could be seen as “wrong”, we feel a strong need to justify our behaviour in terms of higher ideals. It is rare for someone who acts purely in their own self-interest to justify those actions by saying simply that they wanted to engage in those actions. It’s even rarer still for someone who is questioned about the moral basis of their actions to fail to understand the question, or to respond in a way that the questioner is unable to understand[2]. Even the most unequivocally self-interested and destructive acts in history have always been justified in terms of a higher ideal. Hitler’s invasion of Poland was conducted to save the German people; the Japanese invasion of Manchuria was carried out to bring “earthly paradise” to the Chinese people; the colonization of India was part of Britain’s civilizing mission, carried out for the benefit of the pitiable natives; and, in more recent times, the United States’ invasion of Iraq was carried out to bring democracy to the Middle East (once arguments about Weapons of Mass Destruction were conveniently forgotten). In each case, the moral argument is universally intelligible, and allows for counter-argument, for discussion, and, importantly, for a consensus to be reached on what is best for all, and on the kind of society that is most just. Again, the shared moral sense allows for the possibility that harmonious relations could arise under conditions of freedom.

These three cognitive systems (among others) form part of our fundamental human nature, an understanding of which, as Noam Chomsky has observed, is the basis of all arguments for and against the feasibility of particular forms of social organisation. The science of human nature is in its infancy, and further systematic investigation of the extent and limits of our nature is necessary before we can definitively differentiate between what is feasible and what is purely utopian. In the meantime, it is reasonable to tentatively conclude that what we currently know about our fundamental nature does not preclude the possibility that a society could function in the absence of concentrated power. We have tendencies towards collective, co-ordinated and pro-social enterprise, which exist alongside certain tendencies toward personal self-interest and egotism. It is within our control to foster the former tendencies and suppress the latter, and to create a society that is more just, more free, and functions in the interests of all its citizens. History provides us with one hopeful example of this kind of society, which, like our shared psychology, hints at the possibility that freedom from domination and harmony among equals can exist side by side. It seems apt to close this discussion of freedom and chaos with the admiring words of George Orwell describing this society – Anarchist Spain during the Spanish Civil War (1936-1939) – in his Homage to Catalonia:

“When one came straight from England the aspect of Barcelona was something startling and overwhelming. It was the first time that I had ever been in a town where the working class was in the saddle [...] Waiters and shop-walkers looked you in the face and treated you as an equal. Servile and even ceremonial forms of speech had temporarily disappeared. Nobody said ‘Senor’ or ‘Don’ or even ‘Usted’ [the polite form of ‘you’ in Spanish]; everyone called everyone else ‘Comrade’ and said ‘Salud!’ instead of ‘Buenas dias’. Tipping was forbidden by law since the time of Primo de Rivera; almost my first experience was receiving a lecture from a hotel manager for trying to tip a lift-boy [...] All of this was queer and moving. There was much in it that I did not understand, in some ways I did not even like it, but I recognized it immediately as a state of affairs worth fighting for.”

 

[1] Nowhere is this implied equivalence more apparent than in the use of the term “anarchy” itself: “anarchy” literally means “without leader/ruler”, but it is more commonly used to mean a state of disorder where functioning institutions have broken down.

[2] As I’ve remarked to friends, no one has ever tried to justify murder by saying “I killed that person because Hungarian sausages are less aerodynamic than an annoyed moose.”

Powered by Squarespace. Background image by Daniel Skorich.